Black-Scholes-Merton Derivation (Part 1: Portfolio Value Evolution)

First, we define the following variables.

X(t): The value of the portfolio at time t. The portfolio invests in a money market account paying a constant interest rate r and in a stock modeled by geometric Brownian motion

dS(t)=\alpha S(t)\, dt+\sigma S(t)\, dW(t).

\Delta(t): At time t, the portfolio holds \Delta(t) shares of stock.

The remainder of the portfolio value X(t)-\Delta(t)S(t) is invested in the money market account.

The differential dX(t) is due to two factors, the capital gain \Delta(t)\, dS(t) on the stock position and the interest earnings r(X(t)-\Delta(t)S(t))\, dt on the cash position.

Mathematically, we have

\begin{aligned} dX(t)&=\Delta(t)\, dS(t)+r(X(t)-\Delta(t)\, S(t))\, dt\\&=\Delta(t)(\alpha S(t)\, dt+\sigma S(t)\, dW(t))+r(X(t)-\Delta (t)S(t))\, dt\\&=rX(t)\, dt+\Delta(t)(\alpha-r)S(t)\, dt+\Delta(t)\sigma S(t)\, dW(t).\end{aligned}

 

The interpretation of the three terms in the last line above is as follows:

rX(t)\, dt: reflects an average underlying rate of return r on the portfolio

\Delta(t)(\alpha-r)S(t)\, dt: reflects a risk premium \alpha-r for investing in the stock

\Delta(t)\sigma S(t)\, dW(t): a volatility term proportional to the size of the stock investment

Next, we consider the discounted stock price e^{-rt}S(t) and the discounted portfolio value e^{-rt}X(t). We let f(t,x)=e^{-rt}x, and apply the Ito-Doeblin formula (for an Ito process) to get the following.

Differential of the discounted stock price:

\begin{aligned}d(e^{-rt}S(t))&=df(t,S(t))\\&=f_t(t,S(t))\, dt+f_x(t,S(t))\, dS(t)+\frac{1}{2}f_{xx}(t,S(t))\, dS(t)\, dS(t)\\&=-re^{-rt}S(t)\, dt+e^{-rt}\, dS(t)+0\\&=-re^{-rt}S(t)\, dt+e^{-rt}[\alpha S(t)\, dt+\sigma S(t)\, dW(t)]\\&=(\alpha-r)e^{-rt}S(t)\, dt+\sigma e^{-rt}S(t)\, dW(t)\end{aligned}

 

Differential of the discounted portfolio value:

\begin{aligned}d(e^{-rt}X(t))&=df(t,X(t))\\&=f_t(t,X(t))\, dt+f_x(t,X(t))\, dX(t)+\frac{1}{2}f_{xx}(t,X(t))\, dX(t)\, dX(t)\\&=-re^{-rt}X(t)\, dt+e^{-rt}\, dX(t)+0\\&=-re^{-rt}X(t)\, dt+e^{-rt}[rX(t)\, dt+\Delta(t)(\alpha-r)S(t)\, dt+\Delta(t)\sigma S(t)\, dW(t)]\\&=\Delta(t)(\alpha-r)e^{-rt}S(t)\, dt+\Delta(t)\sigma e^{-rt}S(t)\, dW(t)\\&=\Delta(t)\, d(e^{-rt}S(t))\end{aligned}

 

The last line shows that change in the discounted portfolio value is solely due to change in the discounted stock price (note that the term reflecting underlying rate of return r has vanished in the second-last line).

Reference

Shreve, Steven E. Stochastic calculus for finance II: Continuous-time models. Vol. 11. New York: Springer, 2004.

One thought on “Black-Scholes-Merton Derivation (Part 1: Portfolio Value Evolution)”

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Viewing Message: 1 of 1.
Warning

Blog.nus accounts will move to SSO login, tentatively before the start of AY24/25 Sem 2. Once implemented, only current NUS staff and students will be able to log in to Blog.nus. Public blogs remain readable to non-logged in users. (More information.)